Latvia’s Economic Disaster Heralded as a Neoliberal “Success Story”: A Model for Europe and the US?
A generation ago the Chicago
Boys and their financial supporters applauded General Pinochet’s
anti-labor Chile as a success story, thanks mainly to its transformation
of their Social Security into Employee Stock Ownership Plans (ESOPs)
that almost universally were looted by the employer grupos by the end of
the 1970s. In the last decade, the Bush Administration, seeking a
Trojan Horse to privatize Social Security in the United States,
applauded Chile’s disastrous privatization of pension accounts (turning
many over to US financial institutions) even as that nation’s voters
rejected the Pinochetistas largely out of anger at the vast pension
rip-off by high finance.
Today’s most highly celebrated
anti-labor success story is Latvia. Latvia is portrayed as the country
where labor did not fight back, but simply emigrated politely and
quietly. No general strikes, nor destruction of private property or
violence, Latvia is presented as a country where labor had the good
sense to not make a fuss when faced with austerity. Latvians gave up
protest and simply began voting with their backsides (emigration) as the
economy shrank, wage levels were scaled down, and where tax burdens
remained decidedly on the backs of labor, even though recent token
efforts have been made to increase taxes on real estate. The World Bank
applauds Latvia and its Baltic neighbors by placing them high on its
list of “business friendly” economies, even though at times scolding
their social regimes as even too harsh for the Victorian tastes of the
international financial institutions.
Can this really be a model for the
United States or Europe’s remaining social democracies? Or is it simply a
cruel experiment that cannot readily be emulated in larger countries
un-traumatized by Soviet era memories of occupation? One can only dream …
But the dream is attractive enough. In a
page one The New York Times feature article accompanying that paper’s
celebration of the Obama Administration’s Fiscal Cliff commitment to
budget cutting, Andrew Higgins provides the latest attempt to applaud
Latvia’s economic and demographic plunge as the “Latvian Miracle.” The
newspaper thus has fallen in line with the surrealistic Orwellian
attempts to depict Latvia’s austerity and asset stripping as an economic
success as rendered in the brochures distributed by the Institute for
International Finance (the now notorious Peterson bank lobby “think
tank”) and international financial institutions from the IMF to the
European Union banking bureaucracy. What they mean by “success” is
slashing wage levels and leaving the tax burden primarily on labor and
lightly on capital gains, without spurring a revolution or even Greek
style general strikes. The success is one of psy-ops and engineering of
consent Edward Bernays style, rather than of successful economic policy.
Latvia is the country that has come
closest to imposing the Steve Forbes tax and finance model advanced
during his failed Presidential campaign : a two-part tax on wages and
social benefits that are near the highest in the world, while real
estate taxes are well below US and EU averages. Meanwhile, capital
gains are lightly taxed, and the country has become successful as a
capital flight and tax avoidance haven for Russians and other
post-Soviet kleptocrats that has permitted Latvia to “afford”
de-industrialization, depopulation and de-socialization.
Higgins’ article nurtures two enduring
misperceptions of the Latvian Crash of 2008 cultivated by its government
advisors picked from the ranks of global bank lobbyists and austerity
hawks. First, this star pupil of the international financial community
“proves” that austerity works. Second, Latvians have accepted austerity
at the polls. A Potemkin Village of austerity progress has been built by
neoliberal lobbyists such as Anders Aslund for visiting journalists and
policymakers. In the main, these visitors have accepted this
Theresienstadt-like “tour” for reality.
Typically trafficked tales of Latvia as a
Protestant morality play (an image we presented in our June Financial
Times article on Latvia) depict plucky but stoic Balts confronting the
crisis and wage reductions not with Mediterranean histrionics, but by
getting busy with work. This idea appeals to certain smug middle-class
prejudices and stereotypes in countries whose populations have not had
to suffer economic experiments in neoliberal horror. While there is some
truth in the characterization of Balts as taciturn and slow to protest,
the cultural traits argument is a poor attempt at developing a short
hand for explaining Latvia’s situation. They are authored by people
bereft of an on-the-ground understanding of what has happened to Latvia.
Meanwhile, “work” (employment) would be nice, Latvia’s unemployment
remains high at 14.2% despite a significant portion of its population
having departed the country.
Anyone with actual experience in Latvia
will see the dissonance between myth and reality regarding the
government’s response to the crisis. First, Latvians most emphatically
did protest both the corruption and proposed austerity following the
fall 2008 crash. This was most evident at the massive January 13, 2009
protest in Riga attended by 10,000 people. This was followed by a series
of protests by students, teachers, farmers, pensioners and health
workers in the next months.
It is not in the character of neoliberal
regimes to be sympathetic to such protests, peaceful or not. Committed
monetarists, they were not going to yield on policy. So Latvians moved
on to the next stage of protest.
‘No People, No Problem’: the Great Latvian Exodus
A harsh austerity regime was imposed and protests did abate. What happened?
In a word, emigration. At least 10% of
Latvians have left since EU accession in 2004 and access to the Schengen
Zone. This exodus accelerated following the economic crash in late
2008. The problem was evinced in one Latvian student protest placard
that read, “the last student out at the airport, please turn off the
lights!” Latvia’s population is small enough for the bigger EU
countries to absorb its departing workforce. And on balance, the nation
has been experiencing emigration since its independence from the Soviet
Union in 1991, when neoliberal policies replaced a failing Soviet
economy. Yet, rather than lessening over time as one would expect,
Latvia, which can ill afford emigration, saw people leaving in ever
greater numbers nearly two decades out from independence.
Latvians were reproducing at replacement
rates when the USSR collapsed. Its 2.7 million population in 1991
dwindled to an official 2.08 million in 2010 through a combination
emigration and a financial environment too precarious to permit marriage
and children. And, this “official” number from the 2010 census is quite
optimistic. Demographic reports originally showed a figure of 1.88
million in 2010. Some Latvian demographers even stated their belief
that this lower number was inflated. Latvian demographers report
government pressure on census takers to come up with a number above the
psychologically significant 2 million threshold. This success (yet
another neoliberal Potemkin Village illusion) reportedly was achieved,
in part, by using a government website to count Latvians as resident in
the country even when they were just visiting to see relatives or check
on property.
Regardless of the veracity of the lower
or higher numbers, both are unsustainably low and represent a slow
euthanizing of the country. While many Russians quickly left at Latvia’s
independence, most subsequent emigrants have done so for economic
reasons. Within a half-year of the initial protests, emigration
accelerated and the number of children born in the country plunged as
Latvia’s economy crashed and its government intensified fiscal
austerity.
Austerity’s defenders rejoin that the
country had two national elections and could have changed economic
course. But they spin the details that explain just why Latvia’s
policymaking elite have managed to remain remarkably constant over the
past twenty years. Latvia’s two parliamentary elections both before and
since the crisis have turned on endless ethnic politics. Austerity
policy has been associated with mostly ethnic Latvian parties, while
more social democratic alternatives have been associated with ethnic
Russian parties. To be sure, both ethnic communities were divided over
economic policy, but it was mainly the ethnic framing of economic policy
that ensured austerity policies would prevail in a country still
traumatized by the Soviet occupation and divided over what economic
policy to take in the wake of the 2008 crisis.
Latvia’s economic collapse was the
deepest of any nation when the financial bubble burst in 2008. Hot money
flows had inflated its property markets to world-high levels, thanks to
its neoliberal minimal taxation of real estate that was the
complemented by onerous taxation of labor. Given how deep the plunge
was, there was room for the inevitable bounce up thereafter – hailed as a
recovery.
When one looks at the details, the
so-called recovery was centered on four sectors. First, is Latvia’s
correspondent (offshore) banking sector that attracts and processes
capital flight. Already a site for illicit transfer of Soviet oil and
metals to world markets before independence, Latvia became a major
destination for oligarch hot money. The Latvian port of Ventspils was an
export terminal for Russian oil, providing foreign exchange that was a
Soviet and later Russian embezzler’s dream. Figures such as the
notorious Grigory Loutchansky of Latvia and his Nordex became notorious
for money laundering. Even Americans were involved, such as
Loutchansky’s partner, Marc Rich (later pardoned by Bill Clinton) who
later took over the Nordex operation.
The Latvian government signaled its
intentions to defend this offshore banking sector at all costs
(including imposing austerity on its people) when it bailed out Latvia’s
biggest offshore bank, Parex. European Commission and IMF authorities
gave a massive foreign loan for Latvia that in part enabled the
government to function after bailing out Parex and thus its
correspondent (offshore) accounts and continued payment of above-market
interest rates to “favored” (read: “well connected”) customers.
Although not in the league with London,
New York and Zurich as a criminogenic flight capital center, Latvia has
carved out a substantial niche in the global money laundering system.
According to Bloomberg: “As non-European inflows into Cyprus stagnate,
about $1.2 billion flooded into Latvia in the first half of the year.
Non-resident deposits are now $10 billion, about half the total,
regulators say, exceeding 43 percent in Switzerland, according to that
nation’s central bank.” These are big amounts in view of the fact that
Latvia has only about a quarter of Switzerland’s population and merely a
tenth of its GDP. While this activity might make many bankers rich, it
does little to develop Latvia’s economy. Moreover, it represents a
beggar thy neighbor policy that permits Latvia to benefit from taking
capital out of developing post-Soviet neighboring countries.
Second, Latvia’s emergency response to
the crisis was to ratchet up clear cutting of forests. Latvia inherited
massive woodland reserves from the Soviet policy of converting farmland
to forest. Export growth in this category reflects asset stripping
post-Soviet style. That patrimony is being drawn down. While
significant, one must remember that given Latvia’s far northern
latitude, it takes fifty to a hundred years to replace trees to
maturity. So this resource cannot be indefinitely sustained. Moreover,
the move to develop more value-added processing of Latvia’s forests has
been frustratingly slow. Promises by the chief consumers of Latvian logs
(e.g., Sweden and others) to process logs into timber, paper and other
products, have mostly been talk, with little action.
Third, the fact that Latvia’s
neoliberalized economy has been de-industrialized over the past two
decades means that nearly any increase in post-crash manufacturing
represents growth in percentage terms. Latvia has nearly no effective
labor protections, and only the weakest unions to advocate for decent
working conditions and salaries (or even sometimes to be paid at all).
Wages can be pushed down from what already were poverty levels, while
businesses deploy labor in any fashion they see fit, without regulatory
structures to protect workers. Simultaneously, Latvia’s labor costs are
far higher than are economically necessary, thanks to the punishingly
high set of labor and social taxes designed to keep capital gains and
real estate taxes comparatively low. Even so, wages and “flexibility”
have made Latvian labor cheap enough to encourage some enterprise. Yet,
there are also real centers of innovation and entrepreneurial talent,
but they mostly succeed in spite of Latvian government policy, not by
support from it.
Europe’s recent star export performers
on a percent basis have been Latvia and Greece – a metric that makes
sense only as a bounce up from a big post crash . Latvia’s per capita
purchasing power is well below that of even Greece. The modest uptick in
manufacturing and exports is positive, but Latvia still is ranked last
in Europe for innovation and R&D investment as percentages of GDP.
The lack of investment in innovation,combined with anti-labor tax and
finance policy, thus limits manufacturing’s potential for much faster
growth as Latvian labor costs are higher than needed, due to regressive
taxation.
Fourth, there has been growth in the
previously underdeveloped agricultural and transit sectors. This has
been encouraged by food-price inflation in recent years and better
policy and planning from the Ministry of Transportation. Although
transit historically has been among the most corrupt parts of the
Latvian economy and government, centers of excellence have emerged in
that ministry that have leveraged up Latvia’s transit potential.
Russia’s agreement to use its rail lines to permit supply of American
troops in Afghanistan via Latvian ports hasn’t hurt either.
The most revealing part of the New York
Times’ mostly puff piece on behalf of budget cutting that can be seen as
a model for America to grin and bear the coming austerity, only comes
in the concluding comments by economists in Latvia who reported: “The
idea of a Latvian ‘success story’ is ridiculous.” “Latvia is not a model
for anybody.” “You can only do this in a country that is willing to
take serious pain for some time and has a dramatic flexibility in the
labor market.” In short, it can’t be done in any real democracy.
For governments able to ignore the will
of the people (an expanding trend in rich developed countries), the
Latvian model can only be applied if one’s country is:
- Small enough, willing enough, and able
to let at least 10% of population emigrate, headed by the most talented
and multilingual freshly minted graduates;
- Demographically secure enough to see family formation, marriage and birth rates plummet;
- An ethnically divided population that enables politicians to play the ethnic card to distract population from economic issues; and
- A depoliticized Post-Soviet population willing to give up protest after short period.
- Demographically secure enough to see family formation, marriage and birth rates plummet;
- An ethnically divided population that enables politicians to play the ethnic card to distract population from economic issues; and
- A depoliticized Post-Soviet population willing to give up protest after short period.
Any larger country attempting this level
of austerity would need to find an outlet for the some 10% of its
people leaving. For the United States, that would mean countries willing
to take 20 million American workers. Last time the authors checked,
neither Canada nor Mexico had the willingness or capacity to take these
numbers, and not enough American students have yet studied Mandarin to
do China’s laundry.
Latvia still has a well-educated
population with highly developed design sensibilities. Its skilled
workers are known for their creativity and attention to detail. With
better economic policy, less anti-labor tax policy, less subsidy of real
estate and finance and more investment in innovation – the opposite of
what The New York Times celebrates as Latvia’s success story – it could
replicate the successes of its Scandinavian neighbors. The alternative
is for its neoliberalized economy to produce “recovery” in a way
reminiscent of Tacitus’ characterization, put in the mouth of the Celtic
chieftain Calgacus before the battle of Mons Graupius: Rome’s victories
“make a desert and they call it peace.” Neoliberals call austerity and
emigration “stability” and even economic growth and recovery, as long as
people don’t complain or demand an alternative.
Michael Hudson was Professor of Economics and
Director of Research at the Riga Graduate School of Law. He is a
research professor of Economics at University of Missouri, Kansas City,
and a research associate at the Levy Economics Institute of Bard
College. His book summarizing his economic theories, The Bubble and
Beyond <http://www.amazon.com/exec/obidos/ASIN/3981484207/counterpunchmaga <http://www.amazon.com/exec/obidos/ASIN/3981484207/counterpunchmaga> > , is available on Amazon. His latest book is Finance Capitalism and Its Discontents <http://www.amazon.com/exec/obidos/ASIN/3981484215/counterpunchmaga <http://www.amazon.com/exec/obidos/ASIN/3981484215/counterpunchmaga> > . He can be reached via his website, mh@michael-hudson.comJeffrey Sommers is visiting faculty at the Stockholm School of Economics in Riga. He is an Associate Professor of Political Economy & Public Policy at the University of Wisconsin – Milwaukee.
The authors have advised Latvian politicians and government officials up to the Prime Minister level. Both have published extensively in the Latvian press. Additionally, they have written for The Financial Times, The Guardian, and several other text, radio, and television media. Sommers is co-editor and author with Charles Woolfson for the forthcoming Routledge Press volume, The Contradictions of Austerity: The Socio-Economic Costs of the Neoliberal Baltic Model, of which Hudson has a contributing chapter.
No comments:
Post a Comment